Notes from: Amin, A (ed) (1994) Post-Fordism:
A Reader, Blackwell: Oxford
Chapter 1 Amin 'Post-Fordism: models, fantasies and phantoms
of
transition'.
Most
people seem to agree that there has been a
substantial transition since the 1970s. For some people, this is the
information age, for others postmodernity, global interdependence, or
a
new
mercantilism-based society (where the state aids new areas of technical
expertise). It
can also involve more corporate control with banks and corporations
more
dominant. Some people see as flexible specialisation, with a versatile
work
force, flat teams, new social movements, and a new social economy [all these terms arise from Sternberg,
apparently]. All the models assume an end to centralism and mass
markets.
There are
lots of marxist criticisms available,
especially via Capital and Class
[a marxist journal and theoretical school] : for them, the approach is
too
functionalist and
systematic, ignoring the 'non path
dependent, contested and open nature of change' (3). There may be no
clear
breaks, or no binary contrasts (and this
includes criticism of the view that there are now old and new times).
There are
many determinations instead. However, postfordism in the New Times
project
already attempts to synthesise the economic and the cultural, and is
not
without
its critics (including Rustin and Sivanadan). Post-Fordism is clearly a
floating metaphor, involving different emphases.
There are three
broad models of the transition
from the British economy of the 1970s to the present:
there
are also several other important models, including work by Bowles
and
Gintis, a class
based version of regulation theory, Lash and Urry on disorganised
capitalism,
or Harvey on flexible accumulation.
(1) Regulation (a
French school including Aglietta and Lipietz). There are now at least
seven specific variants, but all see the key regulating mechanisms of
economic
life as in decline. Regulating mechanisms are not just economic laws,
but are
'embedded social practices'. Key concepts include the 'regime
of accumulation' (social norms,
relations and forms of exchange which regulate the economy), and the 'mode of regulation' (institutions
and cultural habits which
reproduce the whole capitalist society). There are also 'dominant
industrial paradigms/labour
processes', which combine with regimes of accumulation and modes of
regulation
to produce a specific 'mode of
development'. Finally, there are dominant 'societal
paradigms' which involve political compromises
and hegemonic
patterns of domination and which attempt to integrate the whole
society.
Fordism
can be described as involving intensive
accumulation and monopolistic regulation. It can be analysed further as
involving a specific labour process (mass-production);
a regime of accumulation (economic growth,
economies of scale, mass
market); and a mode of regulation (the
separation of ownership and control, large corporations, the
corporate recognition of trade unions, the management of credit to
sustain
demand, mass consumerism, government intervention in wage policies and
Keynesianism). This is an ideal type, which has always combined with
non-Fordist sections in practice. Fordism produced crises from:
decreasing
productivity (unions limit work, and there
is a loss of
economies of scale); globalization (which
makes national management impossible); growing
social expenditure (on the welfare state);
the end of mass
consumption and new diversity.
Amin
says that the problem with this approach
is that it assumes there is still one general logic of growth and
accumulation,
rather than a set of general struggles and contradictions. Further, it
operates
post hoc, rather than as a predictive theory.
(2)
Neo-Schumpeterian.
[Schumpeter
was an Austrian economist who wrote an early piece praising the
entrepreneur as the innovative element in economic and social systems,
including capitalism,
socialism and democracy {the title of one of his books}] This
approach has some
general links with the regulation school and its take on Fordism,
especially
with its analysis of the 'techno-economic paradigm' as a major regime
of
accumulation, and the 'socio- institutional framework' as the
equivalent of a
mode of regulation. However, it gives greater importance to technology
and the
role of innovative entrepreneurs. These produce sudden quantum leaps in
production followed by changes in social life to diffuse them.
Innovation can
take place in work patterns, but is normally borne by certain 'carrier products' [Toyota? Sony
Walkman?]. The crisis of Fordism arises
from a mismatch between the new technology and the old social
frameworks.
Amin
says the problem with this approach is
that it can look technologically determinist.
(3)
Flexible specialisation.
This takes an
anti-determinist line and sees mass-production as giving way to a set
of
skilled workers producing a variety of customised goods. This system
can
co-exist with mass-production, although it can also be in contradiction
with it
in times of change. Usually this is the result of different choices
made
by key
actors, but these can coalesce into whole historical
'industrial
divides'. According to this view,
mass production dominated the period 1900-1970 but not since. There has
been a
breakdown of
international regulatory mechanisms, more diverse markets, and new
manufacturing techniques, combined with flexible work practices
overcoming
economies of scale.
Amin says
the problem here is that the
approach is too dualistic, it is ambiguous about the autonomy of choice
and the
logic of technology, it tends to see competitiveness as the sole
hallmark of
industrial efficiency, and is far too optimistic in predicting a rosy
flexible
future.
Will
a postfordist future involve networks of
small firms? New forms of integration of management with skilled
workers?
New
forms of decentralisation and involvement, a new
culture, and a new and optimistic 'Yeoman/artisan
democracy'? At the moment, this is found in leading-edge industries
only, such
as in Silicon Valley. It is by no means the only option. The new
forms of work might equally well be regulated by new regimes of
surveillance.
Any
changes are likely to be local solutions reflecting local balances of
power.
There may well be new dual labour markets, and it is likely we will
find
geographical clusters (although Japan
is seen here as a unique paradigm). There are
likely to be both local and global developments, and it is difficult to
predict
which is more likely.
Not
everyone agrees that there will be a new
formation of individualism and fragmentation, and subjectivism, as the
New
Times theorists predict. It is still possible to see a role for
collective
participation and negotiation, with conditions to be fought for.
Harvey's work in
particular sees postmodernist style
as linked to economic changes through a flexible accumulation strategy,
especially in the development of cities -- the 'production
of symbolic capital'. This links with Zukin's
work on
the 'mobilisation of spectacle', in
marinas and shopping malls. They also predict a rise in poverty in cash
realization and the growth of an underclass. This latter option is
unacknowledged by the likes of Mulgan [a New Times theorist and an
optimist]. The same split between
optimistic and
pessimistic possibilities is found in the work of Davis on the
city -- Los Angeles is both the privatisation of space and the
development of a fortress.
Chapter 5 Tomaney, J 'A New
Paradigm of Work Organisation and
Technology'
The three main approaches to understand changes
are flexible specialisation, Japanisation, and new forms of production
in Germany. Overall, there has probably not been a
decisive break, however, there is still a capitalist class and lots of
fundamental continuities with Fordism, including traditions of
industrial
practice which are themselves multiply determined.
Taylor
and Braverman invoke general logics of economic development, and
face the difficulty of reductionism.[Braverman wrote a key marxist
text identifying 'deskilling' as a necessary part of the accumulation
strategy of advanced capitalism]. Taylorism itself may only apply to
fordist
production. Flexible specialisation approaches predict by contrast a
new
skilled humane and flexible workforce, a new stability, the
re-emergence of
the craft paradigm spreading to large industry, and the reunification
of
the stages of conception and production. However, have economies of
scale diminished?
Is
technology that multi-purpose? Large volume production is still needed,
and the
introduction of new technology seems to be going on most quickly within
existing
large-scale organisations, where it is still used to maximise labour
time.
Technology still replaces skill, and routinises labour rather than
releasing
new forms of craft organization. Similar doubts apply to the 'involvement' in Total Quality regimes. There
is still management control, and work intensification is still the real
driver.
Japanisation
invokes a transferable
postfordism, and a more humane work regime. However, the Japanese
economy still
features high-volume production of standardized goods. Is apparently
based on
'flexibility in the utilisation of plants, the minimisation of quality
problems
as they arise, and minimisation of production fllow buffers' (quoting
Jurgens).
But is intensification the Japanese secret? JIT and TQ is designed to
eliminate waste and disruption and job rotation. The non-discriminatory
work
place culture can be seen as a bourgeoisification of the work force [
ie the defusing of worker opposition?] .
The
loyalty to the firm in exchange for lifetime employment and salary paid
according to seniority is really a sign of management dominance, work
intensification or super-exploitation. Is there a genuine class accord
or is
this a sign of union weakness? The superior work conditions are still
seen as a
gift of management, especially in times of labour shortage. There is a
dual
labour market. Lifelong contracts can be seen as limiting transfers of
skill.
JIT is still very exploitative possibly even Taylorist. Japanese work
culture
is best seen as a development into the ergonomics of mass-production,
possible
in the face of serious opposition.
In
western Germany, there seems to be a new form of
production -- 'high-wage/high
productivity coalition'. This involves the re-emergence of skilled work
instead
of automation, and attention to valorisation [adding value to goods]
rather than the old crude
controls. Workers are 'manually gifted,
theoretically talented', and the production system is controlled by a
series of
diagnoses and remedies. But is the West German miracle reductionist and
ahistorical? Does it affect core production only? Skills are still
diminished
while managerial control is not. Technology can be introduced in a
number of
specific conditions, including where it is used to regulate and do
surveillance. The introduction of work teams can bring about
intensification.
Finally, the positive outcomes may be specific to Germany,
which was always less Taylorist, and not to the
general logic of advanced capitalism.
A lot of
the optimistic forecasts seem to
depend on there being some whole logic where employers are forced to
invest in
workers. However, computerisation is fully compatible with
mass-production
and need not involve a reintroduction of craft. New technology is about
control
rather than innovation, and JIT is best seen as a [temporary?]
alternative to full
automation. Even reskilling can involve a new form of integration and
intensification. New developments are best seen as continuous
transformations
rather than spectacular breaks: as a result, marxism can still explain
developments,
especially via theories of machinofacture. Fordism was never universal,
but is
best seen as one solution available in one sector (flow manufacture),
where
time savings were maximised. The era after Fordism is still about
saving. Ever
since the mechanisation of information, 'informational
principles' drive production, determine
work teams, and
decide upon automation. Work is even more integrated as a result,
although the
process is still unevenly applied. The process even affects batch
production,
which it also intensifies (for example
market information gathered by electronic means). Overall what we see
is a
continuation of trends, a flexible Taylorism. Even subjective knowledge
is
harnessed to production, as in TQ. Social integration takes place only
around
production and
provides workers with additional responsibilities for which they are
not
rewarded: for example they are urged to constantly search for a way to
end
production bottlenecks.
Fordism was never
the single factor producing
post-war economic success, and was certainly not universal. The
increase in
demand from a new middle class and from the military was equally
important.
Therefore it is wrong to see Fordism as a necessary logic: it is really
a
particular balance of class forces, a specific deal to integrate
working class
by high wages and standards of living.
However, there might
still be contradictions
since subordination is never total
Chapter
6 Storper, M "Flexible
Specialisation in the US
Film Industry'
Fordism
is a system of vertical integration,
mass production, state oligopoly, welfare state and mass consumerism.
Flexible
specialisation involves the flexible production of goods which is
vertically
disintegrated, with networks of firms, flexible multi-purpose
technology,
and less
technical division of labour. There is a balance of competition and
cooperation, producing regional clusters of agglomerates. Instead of an
industrial
divide approach, there is a tree structure.
Fordism
can be seen as a particular case in US
history rather than representing some logic of
American production. It is now possible to see the end of American
financial
hegemony especially, leaving space for a possible second epoch. The
case-study
of Hollywood shows the possibilities, since the actual
business has been transformed to a far more flexible mode. Hollywood is a
good case study because it is also seen
as at the heart of American industry.
Originally,
films were made using a craft
process which rapidly became a fordist one. The film production
companies were
in fact among the first to adopt fordist techniques. They integrated
production
and distribution, and instituted formula movies. It is possible to see
the
continuity script as a good example of Taylorist division of labour,
which
also had the advantage of breaking actors' skill in improvisation and
thus
control over production [actors shoot a variety of scenes regardless of
their place in the story -- all the scenes at a particular location,
for example -- and then the continuity people edit them
together]. Film production featured an advanced division
of
labour with pre-production and post-production, with their own teams of
specialists. Films moved forward as if on an assembly line leading to
maximum
capacity utilisation. This was the 'studio
system'of the 1920s-40s. The industry produced a
cluster of
workers, oligopoly, and market concentration. It was eventually
destabilised
by: (a) anti-trust legislation which
forced the studios to sell off cinema chains and disrupted their
assured
market; (b) the arrival of television,
which produced a more segmented market, decline in attendances and
profits.
The answer was to
cut production and increase
flexibility. Standardized pieces were dropped, especially shorts and
newsreels.
There was a focus on the spectacular to differentiate cinema from TV,
including
the introduction of Technicolor and Cinerama. Fewer but more expensive
films
were produced instead of volume. Specialised producers now arose,
outside the
control of studios, able to innovate, and also to take advantage of the
casualisation of the work force. The end of long-term contracts ended
the
star
system too -- the best ones could command high salaries which required
further
cost cutting, and a shift of control back towards actors.
Attempts were made
to destabilise the industry
in the 1960s. Hollywood could still colonise overseas distribution
especially in Europe. They were able to dominate TV via
made-for-television pieces. Television itself contracted and spawned a
series
of smaller producers. Studios were still overcapitalised, making them
vulnerable to takeovers and conglomeration. Studio lots were sold to
realize
land values. This led to more location shoots and technical innovations
such as
hand-held cameras, and a new look [eg lo-tech or grimy realist] for the
cinema. Union rules were
broken in the
process, and non-union actors and set workers were employed.
Studios themselves
were unable to concentrate
enough labour to assemble all these skills, leading to
decentralisation, and
joint production with independents. By the 1980s 50 per cent of films
were
produced by independents. Lots of pre-production was contracted out,
including
editing, lighting and special effects.
The industry
required new financial alliances
in order to spread risks, including 'horizontal
integration' (for example film spin-offs).
Other firms
became multi-purpose -- e.g. Cinnabar first built sets then went into
effects,
then produced their own commercials which used their effects. Hollywood was
able to regrow, but as a local cluster,
able to produce a variety of films and other products.
Was there an
underlying logic to all this? In
general, it is a story of shock and uncertainty, leading to
sub-contracting,
seeking out new production techniques, always trying to control
markets. If
market
control fails, subcontractors can grow into specialists and then
innovators,
and then form horizontal networks offering a product variety. These
networks
don't offer internal economies of scale, but other economies instead.
This
became an irreversible change. It is these external economies arising
from
horizontal networks that are crucial, and these have been
undertheorised so
far.
|