IAN GILHESPY
University College of St. Mark and
St. John
Derriford Road
Plymouth
England
PL6 8BH
E-mail: Igilhespy@marjon.ac.uk
Please note that this paper is a
draft version of an article recently published in the International
Journal of Arts Management (Fall, 1999). The final version is copyrighted
to the journal.
Introduction
This paper is one of the outcomes of a research project which was designed in order to investigate whether methods of performance measurement are appropriate and sensitive mechanisms to evaluate the performance of arts and cultural organisations.
The principal aim of this paper is
to present some of the conclusions of a research project, specifically
to present a model of a performance measurement system for application
in cultural organisations. The contention of the paper is that the
objectives of cultural organisations may be rendered down into a
number of strategic options that may be pursued in relation to one another.
And further that the achievement of these strategic options may be
measured with a degree of sensitivity.
Given the confines of the presentation
of a paper it is not possible to report on the research process itself.
Suffice to say that the performance measures presented in the paper have
been tested( except where clearly stated). The derivation of the measures
and of the constituent parts of the policy matrices are to be the
subject of a future publication. This current paper focuses on some
of the conclusions of the research.
The research project was supported by Southern Arts, the regional arts board for the South of England and included literature reviews, large-scale quantitative research using a postal questionnaire into the economic importance and impact of the arts, small-scale qualitative research using a semi-structured interview schedule with key professionals in the management of arts organisations in the South of England and further quantitative research into the rationales of their organisations and further quantitative research with the same key professionals into the development and application of specific measures of performance of cultural organisations.
Context
Lane (1993) has written that the
rapid expansion of the public sector in the 1960s and 1970s implied a basic
change in the relationship between the public and the private spheres.
This rapid expansion meant that ' a considerable portion of the resources
of society is mobilised by national or local governments and allocated
by these bodies to various programmes, thus reducing the scope for markets'(Lane,1993,
pp190). Following this period, the 1980s and 1990s have witnessed
a period of resurgence for economic liberalism in Britain and elsewhere
in the West with a strong political commitment to 'markets and competitive
individualism' (Hutton,1995).
This period has seen the re-examination of some of the functions of the state(Knox et al:1992). This re-eamination is not of the relative merits of a planned economy contra a market economy but, first, of how to strike a balance between the public and private sectors, or as Lane(1993, pp190) puts it ' what types of goods and services are to be allocated by means of the budget and through markets....and are there possibilities for mixing public and private modes of interaction'? Second, this re-examination concerned the evaluation of public sector programmes. It is the latter element of this re-examination which is the main focus of this paper.
This re-examination produced government policy to improve methods of accountability in public expenditure(H.M. Treasury, 1983). The basic elements of these methods were that the objectives of any activity in public life should be identified and defined and that appropriate means should be developed by which the achievement of these objectives could be measured. This type of scrutiny is known as performance measurement.
The reason put forward for monitoring or measuring the performance of an organisation which receives public money is to provide information about whether the organisation is achieving what it is supposed to achieve(H.M.Treasury,1983). To this end it became government policy that monitoring systems ( i.e. sets of performance measures) should be developed that are appropriate in the evaluation of the achievement of an organisations objectives(Audit Commission:1986). Monitoring, therefore, was developed as a process which provided data with which evaluation could be made. The output of the monitoring processes, as developed in the early 1980s (Carter:1991), was an analysis of the success of the organisation in the fulfilment of its' objectives. Importantly, in the early 1980s objectives were to be defined by the providers rather than the consumers, a point I shall discuss later in the paper.
In Britain, with the influence of the National Audit Commission and the Chartered Institute of Public Finance and Accountability (C.I.P.F.A.), the triumvirate of economy, efficiency and effectiveness of service - known as the Three 'E's- have become regarded as the fundamentals of monitoring(Jackson and Palmer:1988). These terms are very significant in this paper to the extent that the rather specific meanings they entertain require some elucidation.
First, I shall define efficiency. Efficiency, broadly, has two interrelated uses in this paper. The first use of the term efficiency is a technical one drawn from the literature on performance measurement and considers the best possible relationships between inputs and outputs( Gratton and Taylor,1992). This use of the term states that efficiency is output divided by resources consumed or, alternatively, that efficiency is a measure of unit cost - the cost of inputs divided by the output (Jackson and Palmer,1988).
The second of these uses has been neatly summarised by Towse (1993,pp.3) as follows:
The social efficiency case for intervention in the market is basically that free market forces cannot work to provide the socially optimum outcome.In this use the term efficiency, therefore, relates to what is socially desirable. The second term is effectiveness. The term effectiveness also has a technical meaning in the literature on performance measurement(Jackson and Palmer,1988). Effectiveness is defined as how far the output achieves objectives. The third term is economy. This refers to how actual input costs compare with planned or expected costs(Jackson and Palmer,1988).
In the course of my research I found
it necessary to introduce a fourth 'E' into the analysis, 'E' for equity.
The term equity in this paper is
mainly about the distribution of opportunities to benefit from artistic
activity. To a lesser extent it is also about the distribution of who bears
the costs. This distribution of opportunities takes a number of forms.
The first dimension of distribution is social ( intersocial equity). This
dimension is concerned with the distribution of opportunities amongst different
socio-economic groups, between the genders and amongst ethnic groupings.
This is in part a question of access, that is to say, availability of opportunities
to partake in the arts. But it is also a question of educational
and cultural capital. The sociologist Pierre Bourdieu (1985) has written
extensively on this. The second dimension is regional ( interspatial equity).
Formulae exist that are designed to ensure that health and educational
provision are equal across the country ( Towse, 1993). No such formula
exists for the provision of the arts because no such policy exists for
the arts(Evans,1995). In fact, it has been policy to concentrate activities
into certain areas(Mulgan and Worpole,1986). There is a third dimension
of equity noted by Bennett(1992) which is to do with equity
over time(intergenerational equity). This dimension of equity has
relevance to the arts in so far as one of the reasons for supporting artistic
and cultural activities with public money is so that they can be
enjoyed by future generations. This could be called cultural sustainability.
I shall use the terms outlined above in relation to the specific performance
indicators that appear later in the paper.
Models and Modelling
A model may be understood as
a simplified version of reality (Wilson et al,1992). The model proposed
in this paper is a model for the evaluation of the performance of cultural
organisations. The design of the model involves the invention
and application of a common rating system for cultural organisations
where sets of objectives - artistic, social, financial, externalities for
instance - must be synthesised into one system of measurement.
The model is intended to be one that has a number of attributes. The model should :
i) incorporate the measurement of a wide range of strategic objectives;In the first instance the design of the model is intended to function in relation to the internal stakeholders(management) of the organisation - a stakeholder being an interested party in an organisation(Wilson et al,1992).
ii) be sensitive to conflicts in the statement of strategic objectives with the use of weighting methods;
iii) combine elements of economy, efficiency and effectiveness(including equity);
iv) be testable.
In the second instance the design of the model is to take account of the expectations for performance that external stakeholder groups may entertain (including those that may not have been consulted in the formulation of policy of specific cultural organisations). The external stakeholder groups in focus are the government agencies involved in funding and accountability procedures.
A critical assessment of the model using the criteria of parsimony, useability, sensitivity and appropriateness is to be the subject of a separate paper.
Strategy and Cultural
Organisations
Cultural organisations make choices.
It was found in the research that these choices are made in a variety of
ways. For some the choices are strategic in so far as they
are made in relation to formal policy ( i.e. with mission statements, for
instance, and/or statements of objectives) which may or may not have been
made with negotiation with other stakeholders. For other organisations
in the study the choices were not strategic but guided by such factors
as inspiration, intuition, common sense and circumstance.
The selection of the base data for the model needs to be made in accordance with the choices available to cultural organisations( whether these choices are explicit at the level of policy or at the level of practice). This includes the choices that are less amenable to quantitative measurement as well as those that are more amenable. The selection of the base data, therefore, will become a matrix of choices available to cultural organisations. This matrix is a policy matrix . The initial part of this discussion will focus on the strategic choices available to the managers of cultural organisations. Other stakeholder groups will be considered later in the paper.
Strategic Choices for
Management
In Table 1 there is a policy matrix.
The choice of policy objectives that make up the matrix is a parsimonious
one. The matrix could be a very long one. The composition of the
matrix is, nevertheless, intended to be one that represents
the range of policy objectives available to the managers of cultural
organisations.
Later in the paper a similar policy matrix is presented for external stakeholders but one which includes prestige, quality of life, economic impact and employment impact.
The policy objectives are shown in
alphabetical order and will be discussed in that order.
_____________________________________________
Table 1 A Policy Matrix
For Managers - The 'Top Ten'
_____________________________________________
Policy Objective
Access Maximisation
Attendance Maximisation
Diversity/Multiculturalism
Economy Maximisation
Education
Excellence
Innovation
Revenue Maximisation
Service Quality Maximisation
Social Cohesion
_____________________________________________
The policy objectives featured in
Table 1 will be discussed in turn each with a table including
lists of performance indicators that may be of potential use
in the evaluation of the achievement of each of the policy objectives.
The performance indicators may be used to assist the evaluation. They are
are not the evaluation itself. This includes those policy objectives that
are more amenable to quantitative analysis than others.
Access Maximisation
Access emerged in the course of
the research as a key social objective for arts organisations meaning
- either or both - access for everyone to the arts and access for those
social groups assumed to be less well represented than other groups in
the audiences/visitors. The implementation of a concessionary pricing structure
is one means of operationalising this objective although this
may be more to do with a welfare framework of provision than an analysis
of visitor patterns(Evans,1995)and willingness to pay (Stabler,1994).
In Britain there have been policies for cultural and leisure provision
that emphasise the need for opportunities for those social groups
which are financially less able to provide for themselves, usually students,
the unemployed and the elderly(Coalter,1988). Interspatial - as opposed
to intersocial - access may apply if the organisation wishes to serve either
its' local or regional population specifically.
The programming of forms of outreach work(using the term broadly to mean work in prisons, retirement homes, rural areas or anywhere that is not the usual site of the organisation) is another means of putting this objective into action as a means of reaching 'new users'. It is a policy which fits the social efficiency argument introduced earlier very well. Performance indicators for outreach work in terms of access are shown in Table 2. The possible outcomes of outreach work are discussed under 'Social Cohesion'.
There may be other means of promoting the attendance of new users which lie outside of the artistic programme such as in advertising or service quality.
The commitment of resources to the
pursuit of access maximisation is a strategic choice which, ipso facto,
means those resources are not spent on the pursuit of other strategic choices
such as revenue maximisation or attendance maximisation. Strategic
choices may be in conflict although some will complement one another. It
will be true of the 'merit good' objectives that revenue maximisation is
curtailed and, probably, attendance maximisation as well. The term
merit good denotes products, services and opportunities which are
meritorious in their own right and need to be supplied( by governments,
usually) even if as Cwi(1982) has noted this 'merit' has different connotations
in different countries according to the degree of consensus about the extent
to which the arts are one of the 'necessary ingredients of a good society'(
Robbins,1963,p.58 quoted by Austen-Smith,1994). This may be expressed by
an estimate of lost revenue and lost attendance. Likewise
promotion expenditure for new users may be in conflict with economy maximisation.
_____________________________________________
Table 2. Access Maximisation
_____________________________________________
|
|
O.A.P./Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Students/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Unemployed/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Children/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Concessions/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
New Visitors/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
(Using Social Surveys) | |
Outreach Costs/Programme Costs | Efficiency |
Outreach Costs/G.O.E.` | Efficieny |
Outreach Attendance*/Total
Attendance |
Effectiveness/Equity |
Local Users/T.A.^ | Effectiveness/Equity |
RegionalUsers/T.A. | Effectiveness/Equity |
Estimate of Lost Revenue | Effectiveness/Equity |
Estimate of Lost Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
|
|
Total Attendance | Effectiveness |
Total Attendance/G.O.E.* | Efficiency |
Subscription/T.A. | Efficiency/Effectiveness |
T.A./Capacity | Efficiency |
Expected Attendance/Actual
Attendance |
Economy |
_____________________________________________
Diversity/Multiculturalism
The policy objective of diversity
in the research data related to both the range of artistic activities and,
perhaps more importantly, to the provision of cultural opportunities which
would not be supplied either by commercial producers of culture -
therefore relating to the 'market failure' argument defined earlier
- or by the traditional funded arts sector, the 'elite' arts.
The policy objective of diversity means giving a cultural voice to those social groups who would otherwise go unheard such as the disabled, for example, and to forms of participatory arts activity where the boundaries of production and consumption would be blurred.
As an artistic objective multiculturalism may be regarded as a particular form of diversity but with, perhaps, the more explicitly political motive of providing representation to ethnic minorities for cultural expression.
The social benefits of multiculturalism are discussed under social cohesion.
There are limits to the desirability of diversity in the artistic programme. Exceeding those limits may lead to a lack of focus for the organisation and/or a failure to pursue artistic quality in chosen activities. Thus, there may be a strategic trade-off between diversity and quality/excellence.
This strategic choice, as with other artistic choices, may involve a reduction in attendance and revenue as well as a decrease in expenditure on other artistic and social objectives.
It may be possible to estimate loss
of attendance and revenue due to the pursuit of diversity.
_____________________________________________
Table 4.Diversity/Multiculturalism
_____________________________________________
|
|
Range of Programme | Effectiveness |
Expenditure on Multiculturalism/Programme Costs | Effectiveness |
Expenditure on Multiculturalism/Gross Operating Expenditure | Effectiveness |
Estimate of Lost Revenue | Effectiveness |
Estimate of Lost Attendance | Effectiveness |
_____________________________________________
Economy Maximisation
Economy maximisation has the status
as a policy objective rather like attendance maximisation. It should
be assumed that organisations wish to pursue this objective unless there
are reasons for not doing so i.e. if it is contrary to other objectives.
_____________________________________________
Table 5.Economy Maximisation
_____________________________________________
|
|
Publicity Costs/Turnover | Economy |
Premises Costs/Turnover | Economy |
Admin.Costs/Turnover | Economy |
Programme Costs/Turnover | Economy |
Salaries/Gross Expenditure | Economy |
Planned Costs/Actual Costs | Economy |
_______________________________
Education
The term education as a policy objective
has a wide range of meanings and the application of the term is at the
discretion of the management of the centre. Education may include
the provision of classes, workshops and possibly outreach provision.
The educational dimension of the work of some cultural organisations
may also go beyond these formal confines into the development of life skills
and social confidence more generally, for instance, in the operation of
user panels. Education is about the re-distribution of cultural
capital which, it is assumed, is distributed unequally. Thus, education
as a policy objective relates to citizenship where citizenship is defined
as:
...that set of practices( juridical, political, economic, and cultural) which define a person as a competent member of society, and which as a consequence shape the flow of resources to persons or social groups.(Turner, 1993, pp.2)
Education is also about the creation
of future audiences for the arts although the benefits of this may not
be returned to the organisation doing the investment. Education is
also the rationale behind the conservation activities of some cultural
organisations, a form of cultural sustainability where existing cultural
opportunities are maintained for future generations. This may be
referred to as the pursuit of intergenerational equity.
_____________________________________________
Table 6.Education
_____________________________________________
|
|
Educational Expenditure/Programme Costs | Effectiveness |
Educational Expenditure/
Gross Operating Expenditure |
Effectiveness |
Outreach Costs/Programme Costs | Efficiency |
Outreach Costs/G.O.E.` | Efficiency |
Estimate of Lost Revenue | Effectiveness |
Estimate of Lost Attendance | Effectiveness |
_____________________________________________
Excellence/Quality
The setting and assessing of standards
of excellence/quality are at this stage - I am concerned at the present
with a model for application by arts managers - to be made by arts professionals
themselves. This is to be an intersubjective process i.e. one to
be negotiated amongst the management team. This negotiation could be informed
by calculations of any possible loss of revenue and attendance engendered
by the programming of artistic activity which is intended to be of high
quality.
_____________________________________________
Table 7.Excellence/Quality
_____________________________________________
|
|
Estimate of Lost Revenue | Effectiveness |
Estimate of Lost Attendance | Effectiveness |
Quality Ratings
(Using Social Surveys) |
Effectiveness |
Willingness to Pay Rating
(Using Social Surveys) |
Effectiveness |
The artistic benefits of innovation
- and possible social benefits - are incalculable as they can only become
known in the uncertain future. This means that although the immediate
cost of innovation may be estimated it is impossible to provide complete
information on all the possible benefits of artistic activity. The
future demand conditions for cultural activity may not be predictable with
any degree of certainty.
_____________________________________________
Table 8. Innovation
_____________________________________________
|
|
Estimate of Lost Revenue | Effectiveness |
Estimate of Lost Attendance | Effectiveness |
New companies in Yearly
Programme |
Effectiveness |
_____________________________________________
Revenue Maximisation
The policy objective of revenue
maximisation is a strategic choice made relative to other policy objectives.
By this I mean that it should be assumed of an organisation - rather like
attendance and economy maximisation. This policy incorporates
all forms of revenue including business and public support.
_____________________________________________
Table 9. Revenue Maximisation
_____________________________________________
|
|
Direct Income/G.O.E | Economy |
Box Office Income/Turnover | Economy |
Sales Revenue/Turnover | Economy |
Business Support/Turnover | Economy |
Box Office Income/T.A | Efficiency |
Sales Revenue/T.A. | Efficiency |
Administration Costs/T.A | Efficiency |
Gross Expenditure/T.A. | Efficiency |
Service quality features may be amenable to analysis using surveys of customer satisfaction.
In Table 10 I have rendered a potentially long list into four key features with examples of each.
A second form of performance indicator
for service quality - like artistic quality - would be the willingness
of the customer to pay more for an increase in quality.
_____________________________________________
Table 10. Service
Quality Maximisation
_____________________________________________
|
|
Quality of Building Design:
Foyer; Bars; Restaurant; Car Parks; Seating; Sightlines. Effectiveness Quality of Sales Products: Food; Drink; Shop Sales. |
Effectiveness |
Quality of Service Elements:
Efficiency of Staff; Friendliness of Staff; Friendliness of Volunteers; Cleanliness of Building |
Effectiveness |
General Features:
Atmosphere Sense of Community |
Effectiveness |
Willingness to Pay Rating
(Using Social Surveys) |
Effectiveness |
_____________________________________________
Social Cohesion
Social cohesion is one of the more
intangible policy objectives that the management of a cultural organisation
may choose to pursue. It is intended that the policy objective incorporates
several elements: the objective of community is one element - although
notoriously difficult to define- and that of multiculturalism(in
this instance multiculturalism as a social rather than artistic objective).
It is a policy objective that relates to the sense of 'publicness'
- that is a sense of collectivity and involvement to counter feelings
of atomisation and individuation - to cultural democracy and
to the encouragement of understanding amongst a range of social groups.
_____________________________________________
Table 11 Social Cohesion
_____________________________________________
|
|
Expenditure on community-oriented
activities/Gross Expenditure |
Efficiency |
Attendance of community-oriented
activities/Total Attendance |
Effectiveness/Equity |
Outreach Expenditure/Gross
Expenditure |
Efficiency |
Outreach Attendance/Total
Attendance |
Effectiveness/Equity |
Attendance by Ethnic Minorities/Total
Attendance
(Using Social Surveys) |
Effectiveness/Equity |
O.A.P./Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Students/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Unemployed/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Children/Total Attendance | Effectiveness/Equity |
Concessions/Total Attendanc | Effectiveness/Equity |
Attendance of User Panels | Effectiveness/Equity |
Number of Volunteers | Effectiveness/Equity |
i) the strategic choices available may be in conflict with each other;A policy matrix for cultural organisations was presented in Table 1. This policy matrix is intended to incorporate all of the policy objectives available to managers identified in the research. It should be possible to locate the particular features of any one plan within this policy matrix.
ii) the strategic choices have a relative importance to each other.Therefore,iii) the strategic choices will require weighting.
The relative importance of the policy
objectives within the plan may be represented in the form of a weighting.
The weighting is a sort of numerical proxy for the significance that
the management of a centre put on their strategic choices.
The relative importance that individual
organisations assign to the policy choices available to them is likely
to be a complex one. If the organisation has formulated a policy document
then the policy choices may be relatively clear. The assignment of weightings
would require considerable judgement. The weightings should be expressed
as decimal points. The decimal points need to add up to one. This
is shown in Table 12.
Using the performance indicators for guidance the management of a centre would then award a score for the achievement of each of the policy objectives. This would again be done with a numerical proxy. The scores would then be recalculated according to their weighting.
The score would then be compared
against a target score and, in due time, against past performance. The
score would be considered in terms of the effects that the external environment
has had on the organisation in the relevant period including those
of competitor organisations( if appropriate). This is part of the process
of strategic management on which there is not space in this paper to elaborate.
_____________________________________________
Table 12. The
Weighting Game
_____________________________________________
|
|
|
|
Access Maximisation | x | y | xy |
Attendance Maximisation | x | y | xy |
Economy Maximisation | x | y | xy |
Diversity | x | y | xy |
Education | x | y | xy |
Excellence | x | y | xy |
Innovation | x | y | xy |
Revenue Maximisation | x | y | xy |
Service Quality Maxim | x | y | xy |
Social Cohesion | x | y | xy |
_____________________________________________
Total 1.00 - xy(total) _____________________________________________ Compare total 'xy' to 'a'(target score). Consider in relation to 'b'(uncontrollable factors). _____________________________________________ 'x','y' and'xy' The discussion of 'x','y' and'xy' rests on one key assumption drawn from economics. This is the assumption that the purpose of public support(i.e.funding) is to alter the behaviour of an organisation(Towse,1993), not merely subsidise existing behaviour. The relevant concept here is that of additionality(Evans,1995). The meaning of additionality is the that output of an organisation will be changed with the provision of public support and may be understood as a sort of surplus. This surplus would not be produced without the public support. In Table 12 the 'x' factor relates to the inputs of the cultural organisation. The allocation of inputs is made according to the policy objectives of the organisation. The allocation of inputs is set by the strategic choices of the organisation( controllable factors ). The estimation of 'x' is at the discretion of the management of the organisation. To assist the calculation of the 'x' factor the management of an organisation may wish to estimate any loss in revenue incurred in the pursuit of its' policy objectives. The estimation of revenue loss is not a precise process but one that depends on the professional management of organisations and their understanding of the demand conditions for the cultural activities in their area. The estimation of the loss in revenue could assist in the calculation of the relative importance of the policy objectives in relation to one another. This process of estimation may be less problematical for those organisations which are trading organisations as opposed to those organisations with a tradition of free entry where there may be no index of cost recovery available. There may, of course, be a number of performance centres within the organisation with distinct responsibilities for the pursuit of different objectives. The 'y' factor relates to the outputs of the cultural organisation. The outputs are the benefits for the consumers(the public) receive. The calculation of 'y' is also an estimation. The 'y' factor - or score - is an estimation of the achievement of each of the policy objectives that the organisation has chosen to pursue. The score is an estimation - rather than a precise figure - as a result of the intangibility of some of the policy objectives of cultural organisations, that performance indicators do not measure the outputs precisely and because of the effects of the external environment( the uncontrollable factors the effects of which a rational organisation will try to limit). The 'xy' calculation is an expression of the relationship between inputs and outputs. The total figure 'xy' is an estimation of the achievement of an organisation in relation to its' objectives. The 'xy' estimations would then be compared to target figures that were set by the organisation including the total figure. The differences between the total figures and the target figures would be considered both in terms of the impact of the external environment and the performance of management itself in the achievement of its objectives. The efficiency of management in achieving its objectives is assessed. A model of a performance measurement
system may be represented in the form of a series of stages and as a flow
diagram.
This should be done in negotiation with relevant external stakeholders. 2. Setting the Objectives:
Again, this should be done in negotiation with relevant external stakeholders. 3. Environmental Analysis:
A form of risk assessment in which conditions which are beyond the decision-makers control are recognised including the possible behaviour of competitors. 4. Strategic Choice(i):
Choices are made to achieve the policy objectives that have been set and weighed(the 'x' factor) in the policy matrix. 5. Strategic Choice(ii):
Relevant performance indicators(dials) are decided upon which will measure the achievement of the policy objectives. 6. Strategic Choice(iii):
Expectations are set for the achievement of the objectives that have been chosen(setting the dials). 7. Strategic Evaluation:
i) An analysis is undertaken of whether
expectations have been achieved, underachieved or exceeded for each
of the policy objectives(reading the dials).
8. Strategic Control Monitor information for feedback for strategic choice. The evaluation of outputs produces
information that may be used to fine-tune the re-distribution
of inputs.
_____________________________________________
Organisations have a number of stakeholders which have an interest of some sort in the operation of the facilities. In the introductory remarks for this paper it was noted that the design of the model would, in the first instance, be made for the internal use of an organisation. The issue arises as to which stakeholders interests are best represented by the performance measurement process being presented here. Benefits and Disbenefits
to the Internal Stakeholders of the Organisation
i) an increase in the clarity of policy objectives;The potential disbenefits for a cultural organisation undertaking this process may be: i) an increase in planning which may not appear to be cost-effective;A Performance Measurement Model for External Stakeholder Groups There are other groups which have an interest - or a stakeholding - in the performance of cultural organisations with different incentives to measure. I shall now go on to address the interests of the external stakeholder groups, or, at least, those government agencies involved in funding and with a responsibility for accountability. A number of attributes for a model of a performance measurement system were noted earlier in the paper. In order to accommodate the interests of external stakeholders the following attribute needs to be added. The model should be : i) responsive to the interests of external stakeholder groups. To achieve this requires the addition
of new elements to the policy matrix( See Table 14). The new
elements are 'Economic Importance and Impact', 'Prestige' and 'Quality
of Life'(Publicness). _____________________________________________
Access Maximisation
At the civic level investment has
taken place in cultural events and infrastructure not only or the expansion
of the arts economy itself but also for the impacts that cultural investment
is purported to have on local economies more generally. This form of investment
has become an element of inter-urban competition for business relocation
and tourism. Investment in culture has become a means of urban regeneration(Bianchini
and Parkinson,1993) although indices of urban regeneration were not within
the framework of the research.
Prestige The state, at both national and local levels, may commit expenditure on cultural activities and institutions for reasons of civic and/or national prestige. Civic and national prestige is both an end in itself( a form of social externality and a means to other ends (in the form of some of economic externalities noted above). _____________________________________________ Table 16. Prestige _____________________________________________
Quality of Life There are constraints on the capacity of users and non-users to express their (dis)satisfaction with public facilities(Mayston,1985). The reasons for this are, first, to do with mobility. By this Mayston (1985)meant that the consumers of public facilities are unlikely to move house in order to seek an improvement in the quality of provision. Second, the ballot box is a general expression of preference of policy-makers or as Jan-Erik Lane(1993,pp.197) puts it: The value of goods and services produced(by public activities) does not show up in the national accounts, simply because the demand for these goods and services is not revealed in standard prices. The willingness to pay shows up in the election process, which does not indicate the marginal value of various goods and services very adequately. These constraints, I would argue,
increase the need for the accountability of public services. One
procedure is to survey public attitudes towards public spending
on the arts and include members of the public who do not use cultural
facilities directly. This is significant if one adopts the principle
that the public should judge the use of public money, what Peacock(1994)refers
to as the 'publicness' of arts expenditure. The responses in
such surveys ( Myerscough,1988 and R.S.G.B.:1991) are positive towards
spending on the arts.
Benefits and Disbenefits to the External Stakeholders The potential benefits for external stakeholders undertaking this process are in some ways like those at the organisational level in that the process may provide information for management and for advocacy purposes. The process may also facilitate comparison. The potential benefits include: i) an increase in the clarity of policy objectives; The potential disbenefits for the external stakeholder vary according the character of the stakeholder but may include:local authorities to the Audit Commission/central government;iii) an increase in the congruence between policy objectives and the strategic choices made to implement the policy objectives, which is to say in the allocation of resources; i) an increase in planning which may not appear to be cost-effective;Ownership and Responsibility in the Performance Measurement Process The initiative in Britain in the early 1980s to develop methods of performance measurement in the public sector was driven by central government. This raises a significant point of discussion about the relationship between the central administration of government and locally constituted ways of life or to put it another way between central control and local autonomy. Bauman(1992) has written on the emergence of the modern state. His argument is that the emergence of the modern state depended on what he refers to as 'universalistic ambitions'. Such ambitions involve a tendency to 'uniform administrative principles'. This tendency implies - necessarily - a move away from that which is not uniform or as he puts it: Popular, locally administered ways of life were now constituted, from the perspective of universalistic ambitions, as retrograde and backward looking, a residue of a different social order to be left behind; as imperfect, immature stages...as grounded in superstition or error...(Bauman,1992, pp11)
My contention in this paper is that the model presented in Table 13 and Figure 1 is able to accommodate the maintenance of local distinctiveness. The policy matrix for organisations(in Table 1.) has an empirical basis in the expression of the objectives of cultural organisations as made by their managers. This means that the organisations may be being judged 'in their own terms'. The interests of the internal stakeholders of management would, therefore, well served by the model system. This is where the particular distinctiveness of cultural organisations may be maintained, where they may retain their 'organic' character to use a term used both by interviewees in the study and by the French economist Lipietz(1992,p.61) when stressing the need to maintain forms of grassroots democracy, for 'communities more centred on themselves.' There are, of course, other stakeholder groups to be considered. And with public services one of these has to be the public themselves. In their document 'Hitting Local Targets - The Public Value of Public Services' (1997,p.3) the Public Management Foundation declare that "Public Services are the principal means through which citizens transact with their government, outside the ballot box. " In this document - and with its predecessor 'The Glue that Binds'(1996) - the demand is made of the need to undertake surveys of satisfaction with public services. Research undertaken by the Public Management Foundation(1997, p.3) of perceptions of satisfaction with the public services of health, policing and education found that " many( of members of the public) believe that local managers should be free of any central target to set service standards which they feel best serve local needs." It is possible that this finding may be transferable to cultural organisations. If so, then the model proposed in this paper , with its emphasis on the bespoke rather than the prescriptive, would facilitate this. There remains, however, something to be said about the character of the transaction between the cultural organisation and the public. In measuring the economic importance and impact of the arts the significance of the user is measured according to how much s/he spends at arts events and facilities. This method can measure how inputs may be turned into throughputs and into economic impacts the functions of the arts economy may be measured according to the criteria of economy and efficiency. However, the method is not designed to measure the value of the involvement of the user in any other way than financial. The user is strictly a consumer. This would seem to undermine the relationship between organisation and user if that relationship is supposed to be an expression of citizenship. The involvement of the user in arts facilities is often that of an active participant, creative and contributory in the process of cultural production. Many of the performance indicators presented in this paper conceptualise the user according to a series of social and geographical characteristics and frequency of use. As such they may again measure the efficiency of arts organisations and, to some degree, effectiveness of service. Stewart and Walsh (1992) have pointed
to what they refer to as the inadequate language of consumerism when employing
that language in the discussion of the provision of public services.
The argument has some application here. The conceptual framework
of the three 'e's - even though it includes 'effectiveness
of service' - is only partially adequate in conceptualising
the complex inter-relationships between the arts organisations and their
users. I would contend that the three 'e's framework , as developed
in the 1980s and into the 1990s, has adopted the language of consumerism.
The notion of consumers is adequately entertained within the parameters
of effectiveness of service when that consumer is understood as a satsified
or disssatisfied customer. However, there is an essence of 'publicness'
that the language of consumerism cannot distil.
It is my contention that the model presented in this paper begins to address this problem by recognising the social benefits that may be produced by the investment of public monies into cultural organisations. The significance of the social benefits of policy objectives such as access maximisation and social cohesion is recognised even though those benefits are less amenable to measurement. References
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||