Immobility in
Britain?
READING GUIDE TO Blanden, J
.Gregg, P. and Machin, S. (2005) Intergenerational Mobility in Europe
and North America, a report supported by the Sutton Trust,
Centre for Economic
Performance, [online] http://cep.lse.ac.uk/about/news/IntergenerationalMobility.pdf
Executive
Summary
Rates of mobility in the UK are
the same as in the USA, but
both are lower compared with Canada and the Nordic nations. Intergenerational mobility fell in the UK,
using data based on cohorts born in 1958 and 1970, but not so in the
USA. Family income is increasingly
associated with
educational attainment rates between the two cohorts: additional
opportunities
are taken up disproportionately by the better off.
The 1970s cohort showed more mixed results in
educational terms—rates of staying on after 16 at school showed more
equality,
but there was widening inequality in terms of access to higher
education. The expansion of higher
education
disproportionately benefited the better off families.
Family income seems to be a major variable
affecting educational outcomes, and its influence might be increasing. Overall, there is a ‘low mobility culture’ in
Britain, and the government needs to make a new effort to equalise
opportunity
at all levels. Educational opportunity
is still the main key to intergenerational mobility.
It is possible to assess mobility in terms of the movements
between 'income slices' [not a term the team uses], constructing a
‘transition matrix’. In the first example,
income distribution was
split into quartiles [slices of income of 25%—lowest 25%, next lowest
25% and
so on]. It is then possible to assess
the movement between these quartiles from class of origin to current
adult occupation
[when people were aged 33 for the 1958 cohort and 30 for the 1970
cohort, to be
precise]. In a fully mobile society, we
would expect to find ¼ of children from each cohort in each new
quartile. That is, if we looked at each
income quartile
when people were aged 30 or 33, we would expect to find 25% of people
from each
of the other quartiles earning that sort of income.
In particular, the richest 25% would have equal
proportion, 25% each, of people born into the other quartiles. We
convert 25% to an index number—0.25. If
there had been no mobility then we would
expect to find 100% of people in each quartile coming from the same
quartile
as their parents -- all the most affluent born into that group
originally. This would give us a value of 100%, or 1.0 in the diagonal
cells
of the four by four table, and a value of zero in all the other cells (
compare with the beautiful 'fluidity matrix' in the Nuffield studies here] .
The actual values found by the
team for the cohort born in
1970 are given in their table one (4). To
take some example cells, 37% of males from
families whose fathers
were located in the poorest quartile stayed in that parental quartile,
and 16%
of them made it into the most affluent quartile ( remember that 25%
would be the figure if mobility was perfect]. For
the richest 25%, 40% of their sons stayed
in that quartile, and 16% managed to enter it from the lowest quartile
as we
just saw. [Note that this data is for males only, a controversial
choice, as we
know from this file, and one which is
not explained in this article].
We can use these data to estimate
the statistical
association [partial correlation] between parental and child outcomes,
which the team call a measure
of intergenerational elasticity [they are economists].
If there is a strong correlation, which would
get a value of 1, this would indicate a strong connection between
parental
income and children’s economic success. The
actual value for the 1970 cohort is 0.29. We
can address the issue of whether this is
good or bad, acceptable or unacceptable by comparing this value to the
corresponding value for other countries.
This is of course going to be
difficult because the data are
not always comparable, and statistics are gathered for different aims. The team has chosen the best available data,
but
recognize that there were still limitations. Nevertheless,
table two (6) showed interesting
differences between
Britain and other countries. In this
table,
the intergenerational elasticity for Britain comes out of a slightly
different
value—0.27, as a result, the authors tell us, of adjusting their data
in order
to ensure comparability across countries and across time.
Compare this value with a higher one for the
USA, 0.29, but much lower ones for other countries, 0.17 for West
Germany, and
0.15 for Finland [, the lower values indicate a weaker correlation
between
parental income and son’s income, just to hammer home the point]. [Note that for some countries, the data on
parental earnings include combined income, not just the father’s
income].
The figure for the USA is
interesting, because America is
often seen as a society with high mobility rates. This
is because the USA has high class
mobility, largely because their class structure has changed
considerably over
time (7) [An interesting difference between the two measures of
mobility: Goldthorpe is going to take another view, as we shall see] . For Britain, parental
income and the link with educational attainment is probably responsible
for the
relative immobility. For the USA, there
seems to be a weaker link, but there are higher returns to education
which
might explain some of the findings. ‘Race’
also has an impact on mobility in the USA. [It
should have been studied in Britain?].
Now we can compare the results
for the two cohorts. The data here are
based on two separate
surveys—the National Child Development Survey and the British Cohort
Survey—with cohorts born in 1958 and 1970 respectively.
The tables comparing the two cohorts are
provided on page 8. Generally, they
indicate that more people remain in their quartiles for the 1970 cohort
[for
example, it looks like 42% of people in the top 25% managed to protect
their
own sons and keep them in the same quartile in the 1970 cohort,
compared to
35% in the 1958 one. While 17% of sons
from the bottom quartile made it into the top quartile in the 1958
cohort, only
11% did so in the 1970 cohort]. Whether we
use the intergenerational elasticity measure, or the correlational
measure, the differences persist. The
American data show no such apparent decline in income mobility over
time.
The team suspects that education
is a major factor
here. It is clearly linked to mobility,
but it is only one factor. They
therefore devise a way to provide figures which are ‘decomposed into
that part [of
mobility] which is related to education and that part which is not’ (9). Further, the education component itself can
be split—into that part which reflects family differences, and that
part which
affects different returns to education. [There
is no detail provided on how these
calculations are developed –
doubtless it is in another article—and it is hard to see the point of
looking at different returns to education, unless these are assumed to
vary
between the different income slices. It
would be more reasonable to assume that they vary according to gender,
that
women’s qualifications do not secure their incomes in the same way that
men’s
do, because women’s occupations are affected by so many other factors,
as we
know. However, this study does not
examine the effects of gender!]. It is
possible to combine the effects from families together with the labour
market
value of the qualification to provide a measure of intergenerational
elasticity
again. [The actual statistic is provided
by ‘the return to education multiplied by the relationship between
parental
income and education, plus the unexplained persistence in income that
is not transmitted
through education’ (9)].
The results are displayed in
table six (10), with each stage
attracting a measure—the return to education, then the relationship
between
parental income and education, both multiplied, and then a value given
to the
factors not related to education. According
to the team, the results showed that
education has an
important role to play, accounting for somewhere between 35% and 40% of
the
difference in intergenerational elasticity between the two cohorts. Secondly, and in more detail, it seems that
two factors are particularly important—the increasing importance of
parental
income and its connection with educational attainment, and a link
between
parent’s incomes and son’s earnings ‘which is not explained by
education’ (10). [A rather embarrassing
finding, surely, given
their earlier insistence on the importance of education?].
Returns to education do not seem to be
significant [I still think they will be for women].
What might explain the connection
between parental income and
attainment of children? The team proposes
to examine
two key stages in an educational career—staying on at school after the
leaving
age [16 in those days], and then gaining access to higher education. The team propose to add some more data, from
another survey, in order to better calculate rates of staying on and
rates of
entry. What they found is that overall,
the rate of staying on after 16 has increased for all groups [note that
we have
a slightly different income slice here, not quartiles but quintiles,
slices of
20% of the population by income]. However,
the rates of staying on for the richest
groups rose faster than
the poorest groups between 1974 and 1986. Then,
the trend was reversed, and the poorest groups
stayed on more
frequently, between 1986 and the early 1990s! The
team think this was the result of more
opportunities and more
courses at the further education level, and the development of the new
GCSE
exam [less socially divisive than the old O level]. [Halsey found that FE was the major vehicle
of opportunity for working class groups too -- yet it is the cinderella
of the post-compulsory sector!]
The issue was whether this
increasing rate then continued
into entry into higher education. The
higher education completion rates by cohort were compared.
Again we find an overall increase, but also
an increased inequality between the lowest income and the highest
income
groups. The lowest income groups
increased their access to higher education by 3% between 1981 and the
1990s. Over the same period, the highest
income groups increased their access by 26%. The
team think that the decline of means-tested
support for university
students was partly responsible, and they worry about the effects of
top up
fees. Generally, however, the point is
that just increasing places available in higher education is not
enough,
because the richest groups tend to get more than their share for their
sons [assuming
a simple model of fully equal shares, each quintile should surely get
20% of HE
places?]. [Also predicted by Halsey, incidentally -- there would be
little working class penetration of universities, even if they
expanded, until middle class demand was satiated]
The team think that education and
income might be related
causally. However, it is also often
argued that family culture is a key factor in educational attainment
[this has
been argued since the Plowden Report at
least, written in 1964]. The team have
developed a model to try and
separate out the effects of income and culture [again it is not clear
how from
this particular paper]. They showed that
there is a causal influence from family income [not just father’s
income then?]—if
family income drops from mean income by one 3rd, this
affects the
chances that children will get zero ‘good’ (A to C grade) GCSEs: the
chances of
this happening increase by 3% or 4%. The
chances of ending up with no degree increase by the same amount. The team suspects that this has changed
between the cohorts, but they cannot show it from the data. Income does have a definite effect, but only
a rather small one compared to family culture [the usual finding in
studies
since Plowden]. It follows that
government policy to reduce child poverty alone will not have an effect
on
educational attainment and therefore on social mobility.
What we need instead is ‘targeted services
and access to the best schools’ (13).
Overall, Britain has relatively
higher stakes of immobility,
on a par with the USA. Educational
expansion alone has not increased equality, but ‘has tended to benefit
children
from affluent families more, and thus reinforced immobility across the
generations’ (14). Income and
educational attainment are causally related, but a redistribution of
income by
itself will not equalise educational attainments. What
is needed instead is much more direct
intervention in educational terms, at all levels, ‘early years, better
schools,
more financial support for postcompulsory education’ (14).
Government policies such as Sure Start,
Excellence in Cities, and the provision of Educational Maintenance
Allowances
are on the right lines, although they must be evaluated, and they have
any
insufficient impact at the moment.
READING GUIDE TO: Goldthorpe, J. &
Jackson, M. (2007) ‘Intergenerational
class mobility in contemporary Britain: political concerns and
empirical
findings’, in British Journal of
Sociology, 58 (4): 525 – 46.
Social mobility has reemerged as
a test of New Labour
policy, but we need good empirical data. Like
the Blanden study, this analysis uses the same
data from the NDCS
and BCS, and makes a link to some later General Household Survey data
as
well. Unlike the Blanden study, this
team found no changes in absolute mobility, but there is a change in
the
balance of upward and downward mobility for men. Relative
mobility stayed the same for men and
women. Overall, there is less long range
mobility, though. The policy
implications are that there are no ways to go back to the higher rates
of
absolute mobility of the 1980s. Instead,
relative mobility rates need to be changed, but this will produce
downward
mobility as well as upward mobility, which will be uncongenial to
politicians (it will upset the middle classes)
Social mobility became a
political issue after New Labour’s
change of policy emphasis from the quality of condition to equality of
opportunity. The idea was that high
rates of mobility would mitigate the social divisions arising from
large
inequalities. This would also be a just
and fair system [classic functionalist meritocratic
arguments in New Labour]. However, there
is less adequate data on
social mobility than ever before. There
is now no data on social origin in the General Household Survey, not
since
1993. The data limits are not
sufficiently acknowledged by politicians, nor have they been by those
who argue
that social mobility rates are falling, like Blanden.
The Blanden findings have been cited by Tony
Blair to reinforce his particular policies, but they are about income
mobility,
not social positions. And the data are
from two snapshots—the cohorts born in 1958 and 1970.
At best this gives us data for only 12 years
of social mobility. [It is a
puzzle to me why Goldthorpe does not attempt to match these findings
back on to
the famous Nuffield studies of 1980. It
is possible to make a rough comparison, for example by comparing the
fluidity
matrices—see appendix below].
The Blanden study found that
earnings at age 30 in the 1970
cohort were still connected to class of origin, more so than for the
1958
group. But this cannot be generalised to
the population as a whole, nor to other forms of social mobility. To demonstrate this, Goldthorpe and Jackson
reworked the same data, acknowledging its limits, and connected it to
some GHS
data for a later period, using measures of intergenerational mobility
in the usual sense: class
mobility, calculated by applying the classic 7 category class scale. This is not necessarily the same as income
mobility: for example income inequalities are widening within classes. If the issue is really about income security
and longer term prospects, economic life chances in general, class is a
better
predictor than income slices gathered as snapshots.
There are some technical issues
too. The data are more complete than for
income,
with fewer missing items, and it becomes possible to include the self
employed,
who were omitted by Blanden because of the unreliability of their
figures for
income. We can examine absolute and
relative mobility, structural and fluidity issues rather than looking
at
quartile [or quintile] incomes, which are already partly relativized.
The data shows class origins and
class destinations as usual. Data on origins was gathered using
the
parental socio economic group at age 11 [note that this study has data
for men
and women, unlike Blanden again. Curiously,
though the data for origins records
paternal occupation
only—female occupations in 1958 would be misleading?].
Socio economic groups had to be recoded to
fit the Goldthorpe class schema, and adjusted, since the NCDS used
quite large
categories. Female occupations were
coded differently—the routine non-manual category was split, and lower
levels (III b) were recorded as non
skilled manual [a working response to some of the earlier criticisms
and
ambiguities about female occupations voiced by Stanworth and others].
Data on destinations
was gathered for both
men and women at age 33. Their present
employment was recorded [not the full Hope-Goldthorpe classification
then --unavailable data?] . Further
adjustments
to coding combined IIIb with VI, and classes I, II and IVa [self
employed
professionals] were considered together as a ‘salariate’.
The BCS data refers to occupation at age 30
and this was also recoded, this time through the SOC90 categories. The sample provided nearly equal numbers of
men and women. There is a slight over
representation
of the salariate, doubtless due to different attrition rates over time. This over-representation would minimise
immobility at the bottom, but the same error affects both databases so
comparisons between them are unaffected.
Absolute
mobility was calculated in two ways, as a total,
then in terms of outflow. Total figures
are provided in the fluidity matrix for men on page 531 [see below]
which shows
the usual pattern of diagonal cells indicating quite a degree of self
recruitment. There is more upward
mobility than downward. This study also
acknowledges horizontal mobility as well, apparently from a recognition
of the
difficulty of organizing social classes into a strict hierarchy, and
allowing
for a certain level of similarity. Generally,
total mobility amounted to about 75% [I
am averaging from
both databases – as you might guess, this implies that the differences
between
them are rather slight. Actual figured are in the appendix below]. Upward mobility
took up about 43% of all mobility, downward about 28%, horizontal
3%.[doesn't add up to 100 because these are proportions of all mobility
-- about 25% of people were immobile] There
is a slight increase in upward mobility
between 1958 and 1970 cohorts, but this is not statistically
significant. The figures indicate a ‘net
outcome of a
decrease in upward mobility together with increases in both downward
and
horizontal mobility’ (531), and there is some statistical significance
here.
The data for women show a very
similar pattern, with
slightly less net upward mobility and slightly more downward and
horizontal
mobility.
In more detail, the figures for
men show more immobility in
movements from I to II than from VI to VII. This
seems to be less long range mobility from
working-class groups into
both service class (especially I) and intermediate class.
There seems to be relatively more short range
downward mobility, from I to II and from IVa and III.
For women, there have ‘negligible’ changes
over time, with a slight rise in total mobility. A
decrease in downward mobility has been
offset by increases in upward mobility and horizontal mobility,
although these
are not statistically significant. There
has been a certain immobility within the salariate, which is
increasingly
noticeable, and more downward mobility from I to II +Iva.
The main feature though is less downward
mobility by daughters of skilled manual groups to unskilled manual
occupations.
Outflow refers to numbers from
different class origins
ending up in classes of destination. When
we calculate this, we have to allow for changes
in the size of
classes over time [just to remind you, if the service class has
expanded a
great deal, it simply must admit more people from lower social classes
of
origin, and this tells us nothing about policies designed to improve
equality
of opportunity]. For men, there have
been substantial changes for those of class VI origin (20% of all men
in 1958,
10% in 1970). Most of these moved up to
class V, some to II +IVa. Thus seem to
be fewer such men in class I in 1970. These
changes affect all men, however, so that class
VI, V, and II +IVa also had fewer men of
all class
origins, a definite decline in the stability of class VI especially
(15% of men
in 1970 as opposed to 24% of men in 1958 – so signs of considerable
structural
change affecting the sizes and stability of classes].
There was also a decline in mobility from VII
to VI over the same period (this is the classic route from unskilled to
skilled
manual class following ‘getting a trade’). There
is also decline in the numbers of self
employed male professionals
(class IVb), from 27% of men in 1958 to 15% in 1970.
For women, there seemed to have
been more positive
opportunities, with a general increase in women’s access to the
salariate. In 1970, 45% of all employed
women were in
that category, almost the same proportion as men, but with a slight
tendency to
gravitate towards the lower levels. Women
are approaching men in terms of middle class
distribution of
occupations. The comparison shows
greater chances for women to enter the salariate whatever their class
origins
(535). This seems to be an effects of changes over time.
Comparing these data with those
from the GHS (a slightly
longer period from the 70s to 1992) reveals consistency.
For men, upward class mobility levels out
from the 1970s onwards, with a slight increase in downward mobility,
with less
change for women overall, but with net upward mobility especially into
the
salariate, and decreasing downward mobility from the salariate.
Thus the comparison shows few
real changes overall, although
there are different patterns, especially when considering men and
women: the
period has been more favourable for the social mobility of women.
Turning to relative mobility, the team persist
with odds ratios
[despite the objections of Saunders] they
begin by comparing the number of
immobile individuals in class I to the number of mobile individuals
from class I,
then class II, III and so on. What you
get is a measure of ‘net association… between
class origins and destinations’ (536) [I’m not sure if this means net
of
changes in the sizes of classes]. An
odds ratio of 1 would indicate no association between origins and
destinations. Any value greater than 1
means a positive association. We are
able then to estimate how much absolute mobility occurred from figures
of
general mobility [which will include the effects of structural changes,
I
think].
Calculations of relative mobility
are based on two
statistical models. The constant social
fluidity (CSF) model assumes constant odds ratios so that any change
must be
structural. The UNIDIFF model assumes
changing odds ratios moving towards or away from one [I don’t really
understand
this but I think what might be happening is a statistical prediction
being made
for each particular case, against which actual observed patterns can be
compared. The statistical predictions
seems to be based on some notion of uniform fluidity.
Try the discussion for yourselves on page 537]. Both can be fitted to the data.
The CSF model seems to fit both male and female
data, which implies that there is a strong possibility that the changes
between
the cohorts was the result of structural changes: CSF explains
96% of the association for men and
94% of the association for women. UNIDIFF also fits the data, and does
no
better than CSF [which is a test of some of the known problems with CSF
discussed
on page 537 – any errors cannot now be explained by CSF failures to
underestimate
fluidity, apparently].
It is still possible that the
general patterns might conceal
important local variations, which led the team to examine odds ratios
in more
detail. They found two interesting
anomalies. First, in class IVb (self
employed
but not professionals) there is a slight shift towards fluidity between
the
cohorts for men (smaller for women), which shows that the levels of
self
recruitment to the self employed group have diminished, allowing people
from more diverse origins to move in. Second,
classes I and VI seem to be becoming less fluid for men and women, a
sign of
less long range mobility in either direction. This
is important, because if [income ?]
inequalities are reducing mobility,
we would expect that to show up with long range mobility first.
Both of these anomalies might
indicate possible trends for
the future, but in general, the data show that the overall picture
stayed the same over
the 12 year period, and the same for the period covered by the GHS for
the
later period. There were fluctuations,
but not trends. Changes were mostly
driven by class structural defects.
Overall, this sort of analysis
shows the point of pursuing
sociological work. For politicians,
absolute mobility is given more importance, probably because it can be
experienced by individuals [and appears in personal stories]. Relative
mobility on the other hand needs much more technical analyses of
fluidity.
To return to the debate, it seems
that mobility is not falling, or at least not yet (540). If anything, there has been a slight increase. There is a picture of female improvement,
rising upward mobility and falling downward mobility, especially since
they
seemed to have increased their share of positions in the salariate. For men, there seems to have been a levelling
out of upward mobility and increasing downward mobility.
So the issue really is a balance between men
and women. Longer term, the structural
effects are important, especially the levelling off of service class
opportunities for men and increased competition from women. The decline in skilled manual employment also
penalises men. [A nasty cynic, not me,
might argue that Goldthorpe has finally focused on female employment
just in
time to save his overall thesis about class mobility!].
There are difficult policy
decisions ahead. For example, recent
changes seem to have
benefited women but not men. The
structural changes cannot easily be reversed [although there is a hint
that
government policies to fully embrace the knowledge economy might
increase the
size of the service class again—actual data here, cited by Brown
and Lauder and others, is very discouraging,
though]. The only way to increase
mobility is therefore to increase fluidity. New
Labour might be prepared to do this. They
seem to think that fluidity is declining in
recent times, although there is no
empirical backing for this: the data show a constancy in fluidity if
anything. The team agrees there is some
possible decline in long range mobility, and this might need to be
increased
again especially for men, through educational reform.
However, if fluidity is increased, downward
mobility must balance upward mobility, by definition.
So the current policies of New
Labour are not really attainable. Earlier
levels of mobility arose more from
structural change than educational expansion. Downward
mobility might lead to a more efficient
than just society, but
the social consequences have been unrecognised so far.
The team still suspects that the political
focus on social mobility serves best to shift attention away from real
inequalities!
The notes are, as usual
fascinating:
Note 6 justifies the inclusion of
I, II and IVa into the
salariate
Note 7 argues the necessity of
subdividing III for women
Note 19 cites a 2004 study were
male and female data were
taken together, and the head of household not define exclusively as a
male. The team argue that this shows a
variable impact, however— a lower position of a male still has a
greater
importance on the female than a higher position of the female has on a
man
[importance in terms of social mobility?]
Note 21 says there is now
increasing evidence of a weakening
association between educational qualifications and class destination,
together
with the new importance given to ‘non cognitive factors’ such as social
skills
and personality. There is a reference
here to an article by Jackson, Goldthorpe and Mills (2005) ‘Education,
Employers and Class Mobility’, Research
in Social Stratification and Mobility, 23: 3-34
There are some superb extra
references to follow up for
anyone interested in this area, including, IC, a new study by Bowles,
Gintis
and Osborn – Groves (2005) Unequal
Chances, Family Background & Economic Success,
Russell Sage: New York
Appendix: fluidity diagrams
Goldthorpe and Jackson (2007)
(I am slightly puzzled since
these cells are normally drawn to scale, but there are two actual
values from the different cohorts -- must be based on an average?)
For comparison, here is the famous social fluidity diagram from the
Nuffield study of 1980 -- men only: NOte that categories have been
combined in the 2007 study though.
|